ECONOMIC VISION
In
the name of Nehru- Rethinking India’s Economic Independence
The Congress,
which is using the Nehruvian tradition to win political legitimacy, has
rejected the essentials
of the Nehruvian economic trajectory which was premised on the idea of winning
economic independence
from foreign capital. By C.P. CHANDRASEKHAR
Jawaharlal
Nehru’s 125th birth anniversary must not divert attention from one important
fact. There has been for around three decades now
an explicit or implicit rejection of and a conscious or unconscious deviation
from the Nehruvian economic vision across a broad
spectrum of India’s political and intellectual elite. This is true not only of
those aligned with the BJP, its predecessor formations and
organisations related to it such as the Rashtriya Swayamsewak Sangh, or to
followers of Ram Manohar Lohia, but of much of the Congress as
well.
This
broadening of the set of those who have distanced themselves from the economic
policy thinking associated with Nehru has been supported
with the argument that the Nehruvian strategy for India was a failure. It may
be useful, therefore, to revisit the Nehru era and
re-examine this assessment, which has facilitated a shift away from what is
described variously as a form of populism branded as socialism or
as just a misplaced attempt at state intervention that created a “licence-permit
raj” pervaded by cronyism and corruption. It must be
noted that in terms of the conventionally used indicators of creditable
economic performance—a combination of reasonably high gross
domestic product (GDP) growth and moderate inflation—the Nehru era can hardly
be considered a failure. In fact, the first decade and a
half after Independence (especially the years after 1956, which marked that
era), were among the best in post- Independence
history when assessed in these terms. This was all the more creditable,
considering that at Independence the new Indian
government had inherited an economy that had witnessed near retrogression for a
long period of time, with agricultural
stagnation
and de-industrialisation, which together had generated a vast and
poverty-stricken reserve of unemployed and
underemployed
labour.
Central
planning
Moreover,
Nehru and his economic advisers did deliver on a number of objectives defined
by their desire to take a few lessons on economic
management from the theory and practice of Central planning. These included
ensuring some degree of investment coordination,
deciding the level and allocation of investment on the basis of a prior plan,
and creating a large public sector to fill the gaps in
infrastructure and capital-intensive industry that existed and were unlikely to
disappear if investment decision-making was left largely to
the private sector. Much effort and money were also invested in creating an
indigenous scientific and technological cadre and an
intellectual elite that can manage the administration and the technological
requirements of a huge and diverse country.
Overall, the
Nehru era was one in which India launched on a globally unprecedented economic
and political experiment. Despite its geographical
size, its large population, its social diversity and its extremely low level of
per capita income, the post-Independence government
under Nehru’s leadership chose to pursue development based on a mixed economy
within the framework of a parliamentary
democracy. Given the circumstances of the time, this was a strategy that erred
in the direction of economic and political balance,
rather than towards excessive state intervention or laissez-faire. There was no
willingness to give the market mechanism an overwhelming
role, because the experience during the colonial years had made clear that the “market”
was by no means benign, but a weapon of
domination that had benefited in particular the British state and British
capital. Neither was there any thought of nationalising all wealth and
establishing a command economy in which a centralised state agency coordinated
investment and influenced
distribution. The best economic minds from across the world, driven by the
post-War obsession with reconstruction and development
as means to an enduring peace, came to India to study and participate in this
remarkable experiment. Elements of
failure
The elements
of failure in the Nehru era lay elsewhere. First, there is the fact that the
growth trajectory on which the Nehruvian strategy had
placed India could not be sustained. No sooner had Nehru left the scene than
India experienced the two consecutive bad harvests of
the mid-1960s, ran into a balance of payments problem, had to devalue the
rupee, and look to the Bretton Woods institutions
for balance of payments support. That crisis precipitated a long period of
close to 15 years when Indian industry went into a phase of
secular stagnation. Compared with other developing countries such as South
Korea, India seemed caught in a low-growth trap.
As a result,
even after six and a half decades, the promise of successful industrial
development has remained unrealised. The most obvious
indicators of that are the inadequate diversification of India’s production
structure away from agriculture to industry and the rather
premature and rapid diversification into services that has occurred in recent
decades. By 1985, industry contributed 45 per cent of the GDP in
Brazil, 43 per cent in China, 26 per cent in India, 36 per cent in Indonesia,
39 per cent in South Korea, 39 per cent in Malaysia, and
32 per cent in Thailand. Diversification of production towards industry was
much more successful in other similarly placed
developing countries than in India.
The second
indicator of failure was the evidence that the effort of the interventionist
regime to address asset inequality and curb industrial
monopoly clearly failed. This was recognised in a range of official reports
such as the P.C. Mahalanobis Committee Report on the
Distribution of Income and Levels of Living (1964), the Monopolies Inquiry
(K.C. Dasgupta) Commission Report (1965), the Hazari Committee
Report on Industrial Planning and Licensing Policy (1967) and the Industrial
Licensing Policy Inquiry Committee (Dutt Committee)
Report (1969).
The third was
the failure of the strategy to resolve India’s external vulnerability,
resulting in the erosion of the huge sterling reserves that India
had accumulated with the Bank of England during the Second World War (as
payment for India’s contribution to the War effort) and
was transferred to India after Independence. Those reserves were exhausted by
the mid-1950s, resulting in balance of payments
stringency which then exploded in the form of the mid-1960s balance of payments
crisis. Finally,
there was evidence at the end of two decades after Independence that the battle
against deprivation was more lost than won.
Even today,
for example, a quarter of the world’s hungry live in this country, it hosts
about two-fifths or more of children less than the age of five
who are malnourished, and it has an infant mortality rate which is double that
of Indonesia’s and equal to that of Haiti’s. The reasons
for this failure did not really lie in the nature of the strategy. Rather, it
was because a number of prerequisites needed to ensure the
success of the strategy, clearly recognised in the policy documents of the
time, were not actually put in place. Two mutually reinforcing
and interrelated contradictions, in particular, structurally limited the
developmental potential of the system. To start with, despite talk
of land reforms, of providing “land to the tiller”, little was done to attack
and redress asset and income inequality in rural India. As a
result, the large mass of peasantry had neither the means nor the incentive to
invest, since they were faced with insecure conditions of
tenure and could retain only a small share of the output they produced. The
prospect of increasing productivity and incomes in
rural India, which was home to the majority of its population, was therefore
limited. The absence of any radical land redistribution
also meant that India remained food insecure and the domestic market,
especially for industrial goods, remained socially narrowly
based, even though the Nehruvian strategy had emphasised growth based on the
domestic market. Under these
circumstances, the growth of the market came to depend on state action. The
state provided domestic capitalists with a large
once-for-all market for manufactures by widening and intensifying protection
and displacing imported goods from the domestic
market. It
also sought to expand that market through its current and capital expenditures
and it supported investment by the domestic
capitalist class through the creation of a number of development banks.
As noted,
this strategy did pay dividends during the decade and a half immediately
following Independence. By the mid-1960s, however, not
only was the once-for-all stimulus offered by import substitution exhausted,
but the ability of the state to continue to provide the
stimulus to growth was also undermined by the second of the contradictions
characterising the process of development.
While the
state within this regime had to maintain rising expenditures in order to keep
the domestic market expanding, it was unwilling,
for fear of alienating the powerful, to mobilise through taxation the resources
needed to finance those expenditures. This contradiction
manifested itself in a fiscal crunch, under which expanded public spending
financed with borrowing resulted either in inflation or
in an external deficit or in a combination of the two. Forced to avoid that
after the crises of the mid-1960s, the government had to limit
and withdraw from its proactive role. As a result, the regime was engulfed in a
deepening crisis that precluded economic dynamism.
Given this
crisis, what was needed was to go back to the drawing board and seek out new
measures to implement a strategy that in itself was
remarkable. There was one difficulty, however. Central to any effort at
economic renewal had to be an effort to redress asset and income
inequality: attack land monopoly through land reforms and reverse the control
over resources in industry and finance that
were
worsening asset and income inequality. Doing that would have not only helped
expand the domestic market, mobilise additional resources for
public spending and revive growth, but also win the Congress the political
legitimacy it had gained from its leadership of the freedom
movement but which it was losing because of its failure to deliver on the
promises it made at Independence.
The Congress
under Indira Gandhi did recognise this imperative but its effort at making the
structural changes for revival, though significant,
were far from adequate. Among the noteworthy measures that the then government
adopted were the effort at trying to curb the
power of domestic and foreign capital through the passage of the Monopolies and
Restrictive Trade Practices Act in 1969 and the Foreign
Exchange Regulation Act in 1973, and, more importantly, by the nationalisation
of 14 major banks in 1969, which when in private hands
were the means by which a large part of the nation’s savings were appropriated
for their use by the big business groups.
But this
effort did not go far enough. This was partly because the economic and
political power of India’s rich had increased considerably
since Independence. But it was also because the Congress had lost its vision as
a party, was riven with contradictions, and had lost its
links with the masses it had mobilised during the freedom movement, which could
have given it the social sanction and political
backing to confront the powerful.
Unable and
unwilling to do the needful to revive the Nehruvian agenda, the Congress, too,
was looking for softer options that could signal renewed economic governance.
Like in many other developing countries, the option chosen was one of relying
on and leveraging foreign
capital to drive growth based on foreign markets rather than the domestic
market. The Nehruvian trajectory, informed by India’s experience
under colonialism, was premised on winning economic independence from foreign
capital. The option that was chosen by the
Congress, especially since the 1980s, amounted to turning its back on that
legacy.
This decision
of the Congress encouraged an elite attack, supported by interests aligned with
international capital, on what came to be called
Nehruvian economics. That attack gained strength from a changed international
economic environment, with substantially enhanced
cross-border flows of foreign capital seeking new avenues for investment in the
so-called “emerging markets”. The
“opportunity”
ostensibly offered by those potential flows provided the basis for a shift
towards liberalisation of trade and foreign investment
policies and a greater reliance on foreign debt.
Interestingly,
the balance of payments crisis that the turn to such policies during the 1980s precipitated in 1991 resulted not in a halt to this reversal
of the Nehruvian agenda, but in an intensification of liberalisation. The private
sector was given free rein. The state was downgraded from leader and regulator
to facilitator of private sector growth. Foreign capital, once viewed with a
sceptical eye, was now embraced. And India, too, began a tempestuous affair
with foreign finance capital. The result has been a huge increase in inequality
and growing economic vulnerability, and only a brief honeymoon with growth.
What is
important to note is that all this was initiated and pursued largely under the
Congress, which still “owns” that strategy. So much so that even when the much
more right-wing NDA governments opted for new measures of liberalisation and
took credit for “reform”, the Congress was quick to claim that this was merely
the implementation of an agenda it had laid out. The difference in economic
policy between the BJP and the Congress is largely that while the former (with
much help from the RSS) uses a communal platform to garner voter support, the
Congress still has to rely primarily on welfare measures (such as the Mahatma
Gandhi National Rural
Employment Guarantee Scheme, or NREGS, or the Food Security Bill), which, too,
it pursues hesitantly.
How then does
one read the eagerness of the Congress to celebrate its Nehruvian tradition? It
is partly to use that tradition and its leadership of
the freedom movement to win political legitimacy, even if it has rejected the
essentials of a Nehruvian economic trajectory that remain unimplemented. It
also has to do with giving legitimacy to its own leadership, which remains at
the top not because it has mobilised mass support through activism but because
of its Nehruvian lineage.
(Published in Frontline.in)
No comments:
Post a Comment