China
needs to return to the original formula of the “four modernisations” propounded
by Zhou Enlai.
It is generally agreed that China’s economic growth is now no
longer being fuelled by net exports of goods and services to
the extent that it was in the few years prior to the 2008 great
financial crisis, but gross capital formation has been an even
greater contributor to such growth than before. Perhaps what
was eventually inevitable has now struck in the form of immense
overcapacity and non-performing loans. Over investment in
commercial and high-end residential property, steel, cement
and automobile capacities and in other manufacturing sub-sectors
is starkly visible, especially in the new uninhabited “ghost
towns.” For economists, the fact that producer prices, especially
the prices of manufactured goods in terms of their valuation
at the time of despatch from the factories, have fallen month
after month over the last three years, drives home the point.
The
question one needs to ask is: Where is this very signifi cant overinvestment
leading to and what needs to be done?
In
terms of the components of aggregate demand, what economic
observers have been advocating for quite some time is that
China should “rebalance” its over-reliance on net exports and
investment in favour of consumption. The fact that the share
of net exports in China’s gross domestic product (GDP) has come
down quite signifi cantly is, of course, the result of the external
demand constraint, especially from the world’s two largest
markets, the United States and Western Europe. But,
regarding
investment, one needs to recall that China was the most
adept of the world’s economies in bringing itself out of the
slump that followed the great fi nancial crisis of 2008. The Chinese
government launched a massive $585 billion stimulus plan
and urged the state-owned banks to be liberal in dishing out new
loans, the two leading to a massive increase in investment in
the years that followed, making up for the decline in the share
of net exports of goods and services in GDP. The share of household
consumption expenditure in GDP has fallen dramatically from
something like 44% in 2002 to 34% in 2013.
The
massive increase in investment spending (as a proportion of
GDP)
is what has kept China’s real GDP growth rate high, though
not as high as the 10.5% average annual fi gure for the first decade of the 21st century. The trend in growth rates now seems
downward, that is, if one were to also include what has been
forecast—from 7.7% in 2012 and 2013 to 7.4% (estimated) in
2014, the lowest in 24 years, and 7.0% (7.1% forecast earlier) in
2015, a fi gure announced on 5 March by the Chinese Premier Li
Keqiang in his opening address to the annual National People’s Congress
in Beijing last week. The fi scal defi cit is expected to rise
this year but the chairperson of the government’s planning agency,
Xu Shaoshi, has stressed that this should not be viewed as a massive stimulus—it
involves an investment spending of 1.6
trillion renminbi ($260 billion) on infrastructural development, including
railways and water conservancy projects, which,
in magnitude, is less than half of the massive stimulus announced
in November 2008.
The
lowering of the 2015 target GDP growth rate to 7.0% from the
7.1% targeted earlier, and the fact that the earlier official forecasts
for 2016 and 2017 expected a further decline reflects a number
of developments, national and international. First, the steady
fall in producer prices of manufactured goods over the last three
years in the face of massive excess capacities in a number of
manufacturing sub-sectors evokes the apprehension of deflation.
Second,
in the face of the fall in the value of a number of major currencies
(e g, the Japanese yen, the euro, the Brazilian real) vis-à-vis
the dollar and the Chinese renminbi, the Chinese central
bank, the People’s Bank of China, anticipating currency wars,
has considered it prudent not to engage in competitive depreciation.
Third, the credit elasticity of aggregate demand seems to
have gone down quite signifi cantly with creditors using much of
the additional loans to roll over existing debt. And lastly, the lower
Chinese GDP forecasts
seem to also take into account the fact
that despite massive quantitative easing by the US
Federal Reserve
earlier, and now the European Central Bank and the Bank of
Japan, the world’s major economies have failed to recover. With
the economies of the Triad (North America, Western Europe,
and Japan) mired in stagnation, China’s economy has been
widely viewed as one of the principal means of lifting the world
economy. The suggested way in the form of China’s economy rebalancing
the components of aggregate demand, namely, the sum
of investment and net exports in favour of household consumption, is
fraught with a fundamental contradiction. It requires a
dismantling of the low-wage, “global labour arbitrage” model of
capital accumulation in global supply chains wherein China is
the world’s assembly hub, for it is only with a very significant increase
in the real wage rate that the path of economic growth can
shift to a mass consumption-led track.
Nevertheless, one needs to be reminded, that the “four modernisations” as originally propounded by Zhou Enlai in 1963 and adopted by Deng Xiaoping in 1978 were to be implemented by the adoption of policies based on the so-called “three imperatives”— social justice, regional balance and command over external relations. Sure, China does not have the kind of mass poverty, misery and degradation that one encounters in other parts of the Third World, but surely social justice calls for a return to the “clay” and “iron rice” bowls, albeit redesigned, and a redistribution of income in favour of workers and peasants.
(Published in www.epw.in)
No comments:
Post a Comment